Largest arb ever based on renegotiated ISDAs?

Tracy Alloway pointed me to this cool story today, about a very large arb. It was an arb of the US Treasury vs. TIPs market. Izzy has previously written about it (#1, #2, #3, #4). The trade was rather simple; you took a position in TIPs, hedged out the inflation, and shorted UST. This was the trade:

Screen Shot 2013 05 02 at 11.35.09 PM Largest arb ever based on renegotiated ISDAs?

And the graph of the mispricing:

Screen Shot 2013 05 02 at 11.49.06 PM Largest arb ever based on renegotiated ISDAs?

Now quite a few words have been written about the trade. What I found particularly interesting about the write-up, though, was how the Barnegat Fund was able to keep the position. They did/do three things: (i) hold 50% of the fund as unencumbered collateral, (ii) returned money to investors in 2005 and 2007 when there were no opportunities, but asked for more in 2008 (and got it) when there were lots of opportunities, (iii) and then there’s this:

When you negotiate an ISDA (the governing document for derivatives) with a counterparty, they begin by sending you a proposal that says if you lose 15% in 1 month, 25% in 3 months or 35% in a year, they have the right to close you out of your position. Our documents have clauses of 20% in 1 month, 30% in 3 months or 40% in a year. That is a slight improvement, but not a huge factor. The big advantage we had over our competition was that if the counterparty wanted to terminate us, it would have to be at mid. Standard ISDAs detail how the counterparty can unwind your trades at their side of the market. This is an invitation for profit for the market maker. They can declare where the “bid” is and sell to themselves at insane levels. Most of our hedge fund competition got destroyed in this fashion in 2008. We hit the triggers, just as most others did in 2008, but no one wanted to close us out at mid. In a perfect example, a huge American bank came to us in 2008 and said that they had looked through all of their ISDAs and they had only given this clause away twice in their history. Barnegat had a huge advantage over the market in that sense.

This is really quite something. Barnegat kept their positions, because the banks couldn’t close them out at their own bids, but had to do it at the mid point. Score one for negotiation skills. This reminds me of a certain London whale, but I guess the lesson to take is that (i) there’s a rather big difference between dealer bid/offer and mid point prices, and (ii) read the contracts you sign and prospectuses for stuff you buy.

Worst graph of the year nomination

A Danish newspaper called Børsen takes the prize for the worst graph I’ve seen in a long time:

Screen Shot 2013 04 29 at 8.15.53 PM Worst graph of the year nomination

It’s a (sad) graph of the price action in Brøndby IF’s stock price (my football club). On the right hand side it’s the price in DKK. On the left hand side… well, I don’t know. I guess it’s the daily price action given the 13.82%-mark, but what about the other numbers? For the last couple of days, maybe? What a mess.

It also gives me a good reason to run one of my favorite xkcd of all time:

Screen Shot 2013 04 29 at 8.18.41 PM Worst graph of the year nomination

Luxembourg AAA? Really?

Pictet with the graph:

Debt to gdp and banking size Luxembourg AAA? Really?

And what’s the verdict from the rating agencies for Luxembourg?

Moody’s: Aaa
S&P: AAA
Fitch: AAA

Err, okay, then. Hat tip Barnejek.

Financial innovation, Rockefeller style

Reading through papers and books of economic history of early financial innovations, I came across this nice little setup.

The year was 1899. Henry Rogers and William Rockefeller wanted to buy Anaconda Copper Company without the expenditure of a single dollar. Here’s how to do that:

  1. Rogers and Rockefeller gave a check for $39 million to Marcus Daly for the Anaconda properties, on the condition that he would deposit it in the National City Bank and leave it untouched for a specified period.
  2. They then set up a paper organization known as Amalgamated Copper Company, with their own clerks as dummy directors, and caused Amalgamated to buy Anaconda — not for cash, but for $75 million in Amalgamated stock which was conveniently printed for the purpose.
  3. From the National City Bank, Rogers and Rockefeller now borrowed $39 million to cover the check they had given to Marcus Daly, and as collateral for this loan they used the $75 million in Amalgamated stock.
  4. They now sold the Amalgamated stock on the market (first haven touted it through their brokers) for $75 million.
  5. With the proceeds, they retired the $39-million loan from National City Bank, and pocketed $36 million as their own profit on the deal.

Simplicity itself, albeit with a fair amount of “staggeringly dishonesty,” as Robert L. Heilbroner writes. This story is from his excellent book, the Worldly Philosophers.

The ECB can deal with bank funding problems

Benoît Cœuré from the ECB is usually the best when it comes to writing (and speaking) about the transmission mechanism and market operations. Since he’s responsible for Market Operations; Payments & Market Infrastructure; and Research that’s probably not too weird.

He gave a speech today in Dublin, which concludes:

In the nearer term, how can the impediments to bank funding of SMEs be addressed? In essence, these impediments are of three types: the banks’ own funding conditions, their perception of the credit risk of their clients, and lack of capital. The ECB does not have a magic wand. The central bank cannot compensate for a shortage, or a misallocation of equity. That is something that has to be addressed, in one form or the other, by other stakeholders. Neither can the central bank alter the credit risk of individual borrowers, although governments can have an impact here through reforms that improve the operating environment of those firms – labour and product market regulation for instance. Where the central bank has a direct role, within its mandate, is primarily with respect to bank funding conditions. Indeed, the ECB has taken and will continue to take appropriate measures to ensure that bank funding is not a source of financial fragmentation or an impediment to bank lending. It is reasonable to think that simultaneous action on all three counts, by the relevant stakeholders in each case, would be mutually reinforcing.

While I’m not entirely convinced that the ECB can’t do more than “continue to take appropriate measures to ensure that bank funding is not a source of financial fragmentation,” I guess he might be using ECB speak to tell us they can. Or maybe not. His slides are important, though. They show some very interesting trends (although not really breaking news): Screen Shot 2013 04 11 at 5.04.21 PM The ECB can deal with bank funding problems Screen Shot 2013 04 11 at 5.04.29 PM The ECB can deal with bank funding problems Screen Shot 2013 04 11 at 5.04.48 PM The ECB can deal with bank funding problems Screen Shot 2013 04 11 at 5.04.59 PM The ECB can deal with bank funding problems

And finally, a chart showing how SMEs fund themselves. This is interesting when thinking about QE in the eurozone as opposed to the EU. The liabilities side of the balance sheet of European corporates is very different:

Screen Shot 2013 04 11 at 5.04.55 PM The ECB can deal with bank funding problems

All slides here.

‘Love letters’

One exam done. So I was reading up on capital controls and a lot of people seem to make the Cyprus-Iceland analogy, which got me thinking about how Icelandic banks used to issue ‘love letters’ to each other. The ‘love letter’ was debt issued by the banks. Then they swapped that debt with other banks, and then used it as collateral for central bank liquidity. Here’s Anne Sibert:

Surprisingly, it was not just the Central Bank of Iceland that was willing to make loans against love letters – the Eurosystem was as well. Between the start of February and the end of April 2008, subsidiaries of the three large Icelandic banks, Kaupthing, Glitnir and Landsbanki, increased their borrowing from the Central Bank of Luxembourg by €2.5 billion. A significant amount of their collateral was in the form of love letters (Hreinsson et al. 2009, p44). It is questionable whether Icelandic bank debt should have been acceptable as collateral in the Eurosystem for any borrower. Given their inter-linkages, the Icelandic banks’ fortunes were far too highly correlated for one Icelandic bank’s debt to be satisfactory collateral against another Icelandic bank’s borrowing.

By late April 2008, the ECB had become concerned about its loans to Icelandic banks and on 25 April, the ECB President, Jean-Claude Trichet, phoned Icelandic central bank governor Davíð Oddsson and demanded a meeting with Icelandic banks and monetary and regulatory authorities (Hreinsson et al. 2009, p44). As a result, an informal agreement was made in Luxembourg on 28th and 29th April to limit the use of love letters as collateral. This proved ineffective. By the end of June, loans to the Icelandic banks had risen sharply to €4.5 billion. At the end of July, the Central Bank of Luxembourg finally prohibited the further use of love letters altogether and lending to Icelandic banks fell back to around €3.5 billion. In the autumn of 2008, five counterparties defaulted on their Eurosystem loans and three of these were subsidiaries of the large Icelandic banks (European Central Bank 2009).

From the ‘Causes of the Collapse of the Icelandic Banks‘ chapter from the Report of the Special Investigation Commission, we have the following tidbit from what happened there (p. 45):

The problem now was not only the unprotected „love letters“ being put forth as collateral for the loans at the ECB but also the currency swap agreements that were in force inside of the asset backed securities. It is clear that the Icelandic banks had angered the governors of the Central Bank of Luxembourg and the European Central Bank. At the end of July the three banks were in fact prohibited from using each others securities as collateral for loans from the European Central Bank which was effective. In general, the conduct of the Icelandic banks which has been described here, can be thought to have played a part in the fact that Iceland became eliminated from the scene of European Central Banks, but this, in return, made it more difficult for the CBI and the Icelandic government to raise liquid funds, see a more detailed discussion later in this chapter.

Also we have these graphs:

Screen Shot 2013 03 29 at 10.16.45 AM Love lettersScreen Shot 2013 03 29 at 10.11.46 AM Love lettersScreen Shot 2013 03 29 at 10.16.43 AM Love lettersScreen Shot 2013 03 29 at 10.16.27 AM Love letters

Which leads us to this announcement from the ECB:

On 20 March 2013 the Governing Council adopted Decision ECB/2013/6 on the rules concerning the use as collateral for Eurosystem monetary policy operations of own-use uncovered government-guaranteed bank bonds. Under this Decision, from 1 March 2015, the use of such bonds issued by the counterparty using them or an entity closely linked to that counterparty as collateral in Eurosystem monetary policy operations will be prevented. The Governing Council also decided to amend the rules on the use of uncovered government-guaranteed bank bonds for the period ending on 28 February 2015. To this end, the Governing Council adopted Guideline ECB/2013/4 on additional temporary measures relating to Eurosystem refinancing operations and eligibility of collateral and amending Guideline ECB/2007/9 (recast), the provisions of which encompass several existing legal acts on temporary measures. Finally, in order to clarify the overall framework, the Governing Council adopted Decision ECB/2013/5 repealing Decisions ECB/2011/4, ECB/2011/10, ECB/2012/32 and ECB/2012/34.

So everything is fine until March 1, 2015. This is — it seems to me — some housekeeping post-financial crisis. In the case of Cyprus, this bit is relevant from the original press release:

As a result, the national central banks of the Eurosystem will now only be allowed to reject eligible uncovered government-guaranteed bank bonds as collateral if they have been issued by the counterparty itself and do not comply with the Eurosystem’s minimum credit rating threshold.

Unlimited liquidity in other words, unless the ECB decide to go all nuclear again.

[And no — this is not a perfect analogy, but it’s kind of interesting since there are a few similarities. Don’t over-interpret it.]

Two-tiered Europe, redux

Relatively silence from this end as of late, given other commitments (mostly exams.) I did stump upon this paper from the ECB yesterday, though, which elaborates on the discussion of the two-tiered Europe. A couple of nice graphs:

Screen Shot 2013 03 26 at 1.01.11 AM Two tiered Europe, redux

Screen Shot 2013 03 26 at 1.01.13 AM Two tiered Europe, reduxAbstract:

The Euro area economic activity and banking sector have shown substantial fragility over the last years with remarkable country heterogeneity. Using detailed data on lending conditions and standards, we analyse how financial fragility has affected the transmission mechanism of the single Euro area monetary policy during the crisis until the end of 2011. The analysis shows that the monetary transmission mechanism has been time-varying and influenced by the financial fragility of the sovereigns, banks, firms and households. The impact of monetary policy on aggregate output is stronger during the financial crisis, especially in countries facing increased sovereign financial distress. This amplification mechanism, moreover, operates mainly through the credit channel, both the bank lending and the non-financial borrower balance-sheet channel. Our results suggest that the bank-lending channel has been partly mitigated by the ECB nonstandard monetary policy interventions. At the same time, when looking at the transmission through banks of different sizes, it seems that, until the end of 2011, the impact of credit frictions of borrowers have not been significantly reduced, especially in distressed countries. Since small banks tend to lend primarily to SME, we infer that the policies adopted until the end of 2011 might have fallen short of reducing credit availability problems stemming from deteriorated firm net worth and risk conditions, especially for small firms in countries under stress.

Cyprus deposit tax reading [updated]

Much has been written today on the deal from last night, and I don’t have anything to add, except to say that the deposit tax on small depositors is a very, very dangerous route to take… Here are the best links to explain why:

Will update. Links in ~chronological order. In pictures [hat tips Mark Dow and Aurelija Augulyte]:Graphed Cyprus deposit tax reading [updated]   Learn to swim Cyprus deposit tax reading [updated]

Banks’ CA holdings, excess reserves, and recourse at the deposit facility

From the ECB’s monthly bulletin, out yesterday.

Screen Shot 2013 03 15 at 2.19.06 AM Banks CA holdings, excess reserves, and recourse at the deposit facility

Happy Pi day!

I didn’t know this was a thing, but it is awesome. Today is Pi day in the US (3.14) and Europe will have it’s Pi day on July 22 (22/7). It’s also Albert Einstein’s birthday today. Here’s Climateer with more:

We first used this on March 14, 2009:

Also known as Talk Like a Physicist Day. A reader emails:

image 807 Happy Pi day!

From: TalkLikeAPhysicist.com

Thanks doc!

Much more here:
March 14: It’s Albert Einstein’s Birthday! (it’s also Pi day) — Climateer